首页 500强 活动 榜单 商业 科技 领导力 专题 品牌中心
杂志订阅

生产率下降到75年来最低,美国公司的首席执行官向居家办公宣战

Jane Thier
2023-05-08

经济专家格雷戈里·达科说,生产率的回升将是解决当前许多经济问题的关键。

文本设置
小号
默认
大号
Plus(0条)

图片来源:TARA MOORE - GETTY IMAGES

我们度过了艰难的三年。百年一遇的新冠疫情夺走了数百万人的生命,全球经济实际上陷入停顿,而在商业领域,美国出现了近代史上不曾有过的裁员潮。我们重回相对意义上的基准线的过程也经历了波折,例如转为远程办公的重大变化,然后才半恢复正常。世界卫生组织(World Health Organization)在5月5日宣布,经过了三年多之后,新冠终于不再构成紧急突发事件,为这一段漫长的旅程画上了一个标志符。曾经有一段时间,在恐慌和悲剧中,工人们比以往任何时候都更有效率。然而,今时不同往日了。

战略咨询公司安永-博智隆(EY-Parthenon)以美国联邦劳工统计局(Bureau of Labor Statistics)的数据进行的研究显示,美国的全国生产率已经连续五个季度同比下滑。追溯至1948年的数据,这种情况从未发生过。

为了弄清楚为什么会出现这种情况,《财富》杂志采访了安永-博智隆的首席经济学家格雷戈里·达科。安永(EY)是全球“四大”会计咨询公司之一,博智隆(Parthenon)是其全球战略咨询部门。达科围绕远程办公和新冠疫情对劳动力市场的影响发表了大量文章和观点。他说,低生产率反映了被高通胀塑造的当前环境。达科表示,远程办公确实是一个需要考虑的因素,但并不是唯一的因素。

达科于5月4日在推特(Twitter)上称,生产率的下降加剧了薪酬压力,推高了单位劳动力成本。“问题在于,不存在提高生产力的魔杖。”他写道,“通过裁员和压缩工资增长来削减成本通常更容易,执行起来也更快。”

数据背后

安永发现,今年第一季度美国生产率较去年下降2.7%。同比下降了0.9%。与此同时,季度产出略有增长(0.2%),工作时间增长了3%。这意味着人们的工作时间更长了,却几乎没有生产出更多的产品,因为他们的生产力已经不如从前。

“当产出增速超过劳动力增速时,说明当下的生产率环境走强。”达科向《财富》杂志解释道:“如果情况正好相反,即产出增长缓慢,但劳动力增长强劲,那么生产率环境就很弱。”

达科表示,生产率的回升将是解决当前许多经济问题的关键,因为这将提振供应,从而降低通胀压力。

他说,在过去的五六个季度里,尽管美国的劳动力市场恢复了活力,就业机会持续增加,但经济活动一直低迷。达科还指出,人们的工作时间更长了,因此劳动力利用率也提高了。本季度单位劳动力成本增长6.3%,薪酬增长3.4%。这些因素的结合为完美风暴的形成创造了条件:生产率连续五个季度低迷,这是第二次世界大战(World War II)后的第一次。

达科承认,客户告诉他,远程工作可能会让员工工作不那么努力。达科说:“我们从各行各业的客户那里都听到了类似的故事,即新的工作环境导致生产率下降。”他承认,不完美的混合办公安排可能是导致生产率下降的其中一个原因。

摩根大通(JPMorgan)的杰米·戴蒙和赛富时(Salesforce)的马克·贝尼奥夫等一批首席执行官认为,线下办公的员工比远程办公的同事做得更多、更好。戴蒙认为,长期远程办公并不适合大多数员工;而贝尼奥夫则表示,线下办公的员工表现一直都更好。摩根大通和科技巨头赛富时一直在念叨着让员工重返办公室,但都屈服了,选择了混合办公——至少目前如此。

然而,达科强调了另一个他认为经济学家经常低估的因素,那就是,在过去的18个月里,劳动力的流动是“巨大的”。他指出,最近的美国劳工统计局与职位空缺数和劳工流动调查报告(JOLTS)发现,职位空缺数量、雇佣率和辞职率都达到了历史新高。

达科表示:“这说明,从根本上来说,雇主很难通过培训来让员工达到新冠疫情前正常的生产率水平。”

新冠疫情袭来时,导致提前退休、劳动力大规模退出市场、大规模跳槽的风潮同时出现,引发了被称为“大辞职潮”(great resignation)和“劳动力短缺”(labor shortage)的现象。上述因素叠加,造成了生产率的疲软。

他说:“因为人们跳槽太频繁了,所以没有机会让他们真正提升到以前的员工所能达到的速度或效率。”换句话说:过高的流失率一直是生产率低迷的一个关键因素,尽管没有得到充分重视。

尽管如此,达科乐观地认为,今年的数字将再次趋于正常。

他说:“生产率是我们走出困境的关键。”达科将当前的环境描述为一种束缚:供应链束缚、劳动力束缚和资本束缚。生产率的提高将减轻上述每一项束缚,同时也会减轻成本压力。

“生产率低迷损害经济的原因不仅在于它限制了供应;它还会导致通胀压力。”他说:“想想看:一名在职员工是有成本的。他们必须得到报酬。给付的工资由他们的产出抵消。雇主看重的是他们为每单位产出支付了多少钱。这就是单位劳动力成本。”

总体看来,很难确定弹性工作制将如何影响生产率,进而影响单位劳动力成本。但是“远程工作和灵活工作的整体理念是提升人们的产出,”达科说。

当然,现实并不总是按照计划进行。员工们会利用灵活的工作时间做一些他们本来在工作日没有时间做的事情,比如洗衣服和买东西,或者不得不委托别人做的事情,例如照顾孩子和老人。戴蒙和贝尼奥夫会以此来证明远程办公的效率较低,因为员工们在做杂务,而不是工作。

现在,达科表示,他乐观地认为,员工和老板正在走向平衡,各方都在努力尽可能高效地在预期时间内完成工作。他补充道,这将意味着生产率的提升。

解决信任问题

达科说,弹性工作制的问题归根结底在于信任。

“你是否信任你的员工远程办公时和在办公室一样工作、一样产出?”他问道。“一些领导相信。在办公室工作是否更有效率取决于很多因素——比如你所在的行业,你雇佣的人。”

但与制造业工作不同,对许多白领工作而言,一个不可避免的事实是:办公室不是必不可少的。工作可以远程完成。他说,问题是,是否相信员工真的在工作?

这个问题的答案可能至关重要。达科指出,随着劳动力市场降温,就业增长减慢,整体经济放缓,“议价能力将逐渐从员工手中转移回雇主手中。”

达科说,就目前情况而言,他认为混合办公可能会继续存在,但现场办公的团队将脱颖而出。

“如果劳动力市场放缓,我们可能就会看到,在办公室工作的比重会提升至3天到4天,而不是1天到2天。”他说,“我认为不一定会是要么全做要么全不做的选择。”

达科称,这将对美联储(Federal Reserve)和货币政策产生重大影响。“在其他条件相同的情况下,我们将面临高通胀压力,因此美联储可能会更加强硬。”隆隆作响的银行业危机凸显了强硬的美联储对经济的危害。

在达科看来,生产率是解答这个谜题时缺失的那部分,因为它能够缓解通胀压力。“如果生产率不提升,我们就将看到美联储的行动更趋鹰派,而非鸽派。”(财富中文网)

译者:Agatha

我们度过了艰难的三年。百年一遇的新冠疫情夺走了数百万人的生命,全球经济实际上陷入停顿,而在商业领域,美国出现了近代史上不曾有过的裁员潮。我们重回相对意义上的基准线的过程也经历了波折,例如转为远程办公的重大变化,然后才半恢复正常。世界卫生组织(World Health Organization)在5月5日宣布,经过了三年多之后,新冠终于不再构成紧急突发事件,为这一段漫长的旅程画上了一个标志符。曾经有一段时间,在恐慌和悲剧中,工人们比以往任何时候都更有效率。然而,今时不同往日了。

战略咨询公司安永-博智隆(EY-Parthenon)以美国联邦劳工统计局(Bureau of Labor Statistics)的数据进行的研究显示,美国的全国生产率已经连续五个季度同比下滑。追溯至1948年的数据,这种情况从未发生过。

为了弄清楚为什么会出现这种情况,《财富》杂志采访了安永-博智隆的首席经济学家格雷戈里·达科。安永(EY)是全球“四大”会计咨询公司之一,博智隆(Parthenon)是其全球战略咨询部门。达科围绕远程办公和新冠疫情对劳动力市场的影响发表了大量文章和观点。他说,低生产率反映了被高通胀塑造的当前环境。达科表示,远程办公确实是一个需要考虑的因素,但并不是唯一的因素。

达科于5月4日在推特(Twitter)上称,生产率的下降加剧了薪酬压力,推高了单位劳动力成本。“问题在于,不存在提高生产力的魔杖。”他写道,“通过裁员和压缩工资增长来削减成本通常更容易,执行起来也更快。”

数据背后

安永发现,今年第一季度美国生产率较去年下降2.7%。同比下降了0.9%。与此同时,季度产出略有增长(0.2%),工作时间增长了3%。这意味着人们的工作时间更长了,却几乎没有生产出更多的产品,因为他们的生产力已经不如从前。

“当产出增速超过劳动力增速时,说明当下的生产率环境走强。”达科向《财富》杂志解释道:“如果情况正好相反,即产出增长缓慢,但劳动力增长强劲,那么生产率环境就很弱。”

达科表示,生产率的回升将是解决当前许多经济问题的关键,因为这将提振供应,从而降低通胀压力。

他说,在过去的五六个季度里,尽管美国的劳动力市场恢复了活力,就业机会持续增加,但经济活动一直低迷。达科还指出,人们的工作时间更长了,因此劳动力利用率也提高了。本季度单位劳动力成本增长6.3%,薪酬增长3.4%。这些因素的结合为完美风暴的形成创造了条件:生产率连续五个季度低迷,这是第二次世界大战(World War II)后的第一次。

达科承认,客户告诉他,远程工作可能会让员工工作不那么努力。达科说:“我们从各行各业的客户那里都听到了类似的故事,即新的工作环境导致生产率下降。”他承认,不完美的混合办公安排可能是导致生产率下降的其中一个原因。

摩根大通(JPMorgan)的杰米·戴蒙和赛富时(Salesforce)的马克·贝尼奥夫等一批首席执行官认为,线下办公的员工比远程办公的同事做得更多、更好。戴蒙认为,长期远程办公并不适合大多数员工;而贝尼奥夫则表示,线下办公的员工表现一直都更好。摩根大通和科技巨头赛富时一直在念叨着让员工重返办公室,但都屈服了,选择了混合办公——至少目前如此。

然而,达科强调了另一个他认为经济学家经常低估的因素,那就是,在过去的18个月里,劳动力的流动是“巨大的”。他指出,最近的美国劳工统计局与职位空缺数和劳工流动调查报告(JOLTS)发现,职位空缺数量、雇佣率和辞职率都达到了历史新高。

达科表示:“这说明,从根本上来说,雇主很难通过培训来让员工达到新冠疫情前正常的生产率水平。”

新冠疫情袭来时,导致提前退休、劳动力大规模退出市场、大规模跳槽的风潮同时出现,引发了被称为“大辞职潮”(great resignation)和“劳动力短缺”(labor shortage)的现象。上述因素叠加,造成了生产率的疲软。

他说:“因为人们跳槽太频繁了,所以没有机会让他们真正提升到以前的员工所能达到的速度或效率。”换句话说:过高的流失率一直是生产率低迷的一个关键因素,尽管没有得到充分重视。

尽管如此,达科乐观地认为,今年的数字将再次趋于正常。

他说:“生产率是我们走出困境的关键。”达科将当前的环境描述为一种束缚:供应链束缚、劳动力束缚和资本束缚。生产率的提高将减轻上述每一项束缚,同时也会减轻成本压力。

“生产率低迷损害经济的原因不仅在于它限制了供应;它还会导致通胀压力。”他说:“想想看:一名在职员工是有成本的。他们必须得到报酬。给付的工资由他们的产出抵消。雇主看重的是他们为每单位产出支付了多少钱。这就是单位劳动力成本。”

总体看来,很难确定弹性工作制将如何影响生产率,进而影响单位劳动力成本。但是“远程工作和灵活工作的整体理念是提升人们的产出,”达科说。

当然,现实并不总是按照计划进行。员工们会利用灵活的工作时间做一些他们本来在工作日没有时间做的事情,比如洗衣服和买东西,或者不得不委托别人做的事情,例如照顾孩子和老人。戴蒙和贝尼奥夫会以此来证明远程办公的效率较低,因为员工们在做杂务,而不是工作。

现在,达科表示,他乐观地认为,员工和老板正在走向平衡,各方都在努力尽可能高效地在预期时间内完成工作。他补充道,这将意味着生产率的提升。

解决信任问题

达科说,弹性工作制的问题归根结底在于信任。

“你是否信任你的员工远程办公时和在办公室一样工作、一样产出?”他问道。“一些领导相信。在办公室工作是否更有效率取决于很多因素——比如你所在的行业,你雇佣的人。”

但与制造业工作不同,对许多白领工作而言,一个不可避免的事实是:办公室不是必不可少的。工作可以远程完成。他说,问题是,是否相信员工真的在工作?

这个问题的答案可能至关重要。达科指出,随着劳动力市场降温,就业增长减慢,整体经济放缓,“议价能力将逐渐从员工手中转移回雇主手中。”

达科说,就目前情况而言,他认为混合办公可能会继续存在,但现场办公的团队将脱颖而出。

“如果劳动力市场放缓,我们可能就会看到,在办公室工作的比重会提升至3天到4天,而不是1天到2天。”他说,“我认为不一定会是要么全做要么全不做的选择。”

达科称,这将对美联储(Federal Reserve)和货币政策产生重大影响。“在其他条件相同的情况下,我们将面临高通胀压力,因此美联储可能会更加强硬。”隆隆作响的银行业危机凸显了强硬的美联储对经济的危害。

在达科看来,生产率是解答这个谜题时缺失的那部分,因为它能够缓解通胀压力。“如果生产率不提升,我们就将看到美联储的行动更趋鹰派,而非鸽派。”(财富中文网)

译者:Agatha

It’s been a rough three years. The globe effectively shut down as a once-per-century pandemic claimed millions of lives, while on the business front, the U.S. saw a layoff wave incomparable in modern history. Working our way back to a relative baseline has come with hiccups, like a huge shift to remote work, and then a semi-return to normal. As a mark of what a long journey it’s been, the World Health Organization declared COVID is no longer an emergency on May 5, after more than three years. But for a while there, amid the panic and tragedy, workers were somehow more productive than ever. Not anymore.

The U.S. has now had five consecutive quarters of year-over-year declines in productivity, according to research from EY-Parthenon, using data from the federal Bureau of Labor Statistics. That has never happened before, in data going back to 1948.

To figure out why this is happening, Fortune spoke with Gregory Daco, chief economist at EY-Parthenon, the global strategy consulting arm of one of the “Big Four” accounting and consulting firms. Daco has written and spoken extensively about remote work and the pandemic’s effect on the labor market. He said the low productivity reflects our current environment, defined by high inflation. Remote work is a real thing to consider, Daco said, but it’s not the only factor.

The drop in productivity, Daco tweeted on May 4, is exacerbating compensation pressures and pushing up unit labor costs. “The difficulty is that there is no magic productivity wand,” he wrote. “And cost-cutting via layoffs and wage growth compression is often ‘easier’ and faster to execute.”

Breaking down the numbers

U.S. productivity plunged 2.7% in the first quarter of this year compared to last year, EY found. That’s a 0.9% year-over-year drop. Concurrently, quarter-over-quarter output grew slightly (0.2%), and hours worked grew 3%. That means people are working longer hours and barely putting out more products, because they just aren’t as productive as they used to be.

“When you have an environment in which output is outpacing labor growth, that’s an environment of stronger productivity,” he explains to Fortune. “When you have the opposite, when output growth is sluggish but labor growth is strong, you have a weak productivity environment.”

A rebound in productivity will be key to solving many of the economy’s current issues, Daco said, as that would lift supply and thereby reduce inflationary pressures.

Over the past five or six quarters, he says, economic activity has been sluggish, even as the country has seen a resilient labor market and continued job gains. People are working longer hours, he adds, so labor utilization has also been higher. Unit labor costs grew 6.3% this quarter, while compensation grew 3.4%. That combination has created conditions for the perfect storm: Weak productivity for five quarters straight, for the first time since post-World War II.

Daco acknowledged hearing from clients that remote work could be making employees, well, work less hard. “From our clients across sectors, we hear similar stories of reduced productivity because of the new work environment,” Daco says. He acknowledged that imperfect hybrid arrangements could be apossible cause of the productivity plummet.

CEOs such as JPMorgan’s Jamie Dimon and Salesforce’s Marc Benioff have argued that in-person workers are simply doing more work, better than their remote colleagues. Dimon says long-term remote work just doesn’t work for most employees; while Benioff says workers in the office consistently perform better. Both the bank and the tech giant have waffled on return-to-office mandates, but both have yielded to a hybrid plan—at least for now.

Daco, however, highlighted another factor, which he says economists often underestimate, is that, over the past 18 months, the churn of labor has been “tremendous.” He points to recent BLS and JOLTS reports, which have found that the number of job openings, hire rates and quit rates have all reached record highs.

“That tells you it’s been very difficult for employers to, essentially, train their employees and bring them up to par with the productivity levels that would have been deemed normal pre-pandemic,” he says.

When the pandemic hit, it brought a combination of early retirement, a mass exit from the workforce, and an avalanche of job-switchers, a phenomenon alternately called “the great resignation” and “the labor shortage.” Taken together, it created a dearth of productivity.

“Because people were job-hopping so regularly, there wasn’t really a chance to bring them up to the speed, or productivity, that a former worker would’ve had,” he says. In other words: the outsize rate of churn has been a key, if under-appreciated, factor in sluggish productivity.

Nonetheless, he’s optimistic numbers will trend towards normal again this year.

“Productivity is the key out of this mess we’ve been in,” he says. He characterizes the current environment as one of constraint: supply-chain constraint, labor constraint, and capital constraint. Increased productivity would alleviate each of those concerns—as well as cost pressures.

“One of the reasons sluggish productivity hurts the economy is not just that it limits supply; it leads to inflationary pressures,” he says. “Think of it like: a working employee has a cost. They have to be paid. That wage is offset by their productivity. What matters to an employer is how much they’re paying per unit of output. That’s unit labor cost.”

Generally, it’s difficult to ascertain how flexible work will impact productivity, and in turn, unit labor costs. But “the whole idea of remote work and flexible work is to allow people to be more productive,” Daco says.

Granted, that hasn’t always worked out according to plan. Workers have been using flexible hours to do things they otherwise wouldn’t have time to do during the workday—like laundry and grocery shopping—or would have had to delegate to someone else—like childcare or elderly care. Those are circumstances Dimon and Benioff would point at to argue remote workers are less productive because they’re doing chores instead of, well, working.

Now, Daco says he’s optimistic that workers and bosses are coming toward an equilibrium, where all sides are trying to be as efficient as possible to get work done in their desired amount of time. That would mean a gain in productivity, he adds.

Addressing the trust factor

The problem with flexible work is, Daco says, it all comes back to trust.

“Do you trust your employees to be working and producing the same as they would be if they’d been in the office?” he asks. “Some leaders believe that. Whether being in the office is more efficient depends on a number of things—your sector, the population you employ.”

But for a lot of white collar jobs, unlike manufacturing jobs, the fact is inescapable: the office isn’t essential. Work can be done remotely. The question is, he says, is there trust that employees are actually working?

The answer may be vital. As the labor market cools, employment growth diminishes, and the broader economy slows down, “that will gradually transfer bargaining power back towards the employer, and away from the employee,” Daco says.

As it stands, Daco said he thinks a hybrid arrangement will likely remain, but in-office cohorts will come out on top.

“We’ll probably see more weight towards three to four days in the office, rather than one or two, if the labor market slows,” he says. “I don’t think it will be all or nothing, necessarily.”

That will have big implications for the Fed and monetary policy, he says. “All else being equal, we’ll have high inflationary pressures, so the Fed will likely be more hawkish.” The rumbling banking crisis underscores the hazards to the economy of a hawkish Fed.

Productivity, in Daco’s view, is the missing part of the puzzle, because it will relax inflationary pressures. “In the absence of that productivity growth, we’ll see the Fed act more hawkish than doveish.”

财富中文网所刊载内容之知识产权为财富媒体知识产权有限公司及/或相关权利人专属所有或持有。未经许可,禁止进行转载、摘编、复制及建立镜像等任何使用。
0条Plus
精彩评论
评论

撰写或查看更多评论

请打开财富Plus APP

前往打开